James Buchanan,
the 2006 Noble Laureate in economics, was born in rural Tennessee, and lived
most of his life in the American South. His paternal grandfather had been a
Confederate cavalryman who, with Populist support, went on to be a Democratic governor
of Tennessee. Buchanan later recalled his boyhood spent reading ‘in
grandfather’s attic piled high with radical pamphlets of the 1890s ... The robber barons were real to me’. By
that time the Buchanan family was living in ‘genteel poverty’ in ‘a huge house…in
varying states of disrepair’. Young James was expected to re-win the lustre of
the family name. But in the approach of world war he was drafted into US Naval Reserve Officers Training Program,
where he experienced the ‘blatant discrimination against
Southerners, Westerners and Mid-westerners’ that radicalised him against the ‘eastern
establishment’. He graduated 6 out of 600, and learned that ‘even unwashed
rednecks of Appalachia could stand to measure with scions of Newport’. One such ‘scion of Newport’ of the same Program was John F Kennedy. To Buchanan’s mind, Kennedy’s triumph in 1960
was no more than the ‘raw injustice’ of ‘a purchased presidency’.
Buchanan was
allocated to the staff of Admiral Nimitz, and there acquired a loathing of the
grand-standing of General Macarthur. In July of 1945 he received an instruction
to arrange for the USS Minneapolis to
pick up ‘a special cargo’. Puzzled by this unusual order, he made out the
dispatch nonetheless. Earlier, while on his leave in his home state, he had heard rumours of the Oak
Ridge plutonium plant, but only after the Hiroshima bombing, did he realise how
he had been one tiny cog in the mechanism of nuclear destruction.
Upon
demobilisation, he enrolled in economics at University of Chicago. He saw
himself as a ‘liberal socialist, but within was weeks he was a free market
advocate. His world view was completed by his study leave in Italy 1955, that
acquainted him with the pathologies of the Italian state, and pitiless realism
of Italian thinkers towards it. The upshot was an outlook on the relation between government
and the economy that was at odds with that of most mid-20th century economists.
They were trustful of government custody
of economic management, but wary of democratic pressures on that. Buchanan
reversed that position; he distrustful of government and hopeful of democracy. Whereas
the standard view saw government as benevolent and competent, in Buchanan’s
‘Public Choice’ position government is no more benevolent than any business. Worse,
it was typically a sole provider of its services, and so was best analysed as a
monopoly. He argued that this interpretation of government implied that even ‘good policy’ would be for the ill; as ‘good policy’ simply allowed the
goose to be plucked less painfully, and so plucked the more fully.
Whereas in the
standard view democracy was the articulation of a ‘general will’ by
majoritarian institutions, to Buchanan democracy was a system of competitive political markets. Parliament is a
market place - a political market place - where exchange between political constituencies
takes. In his classic co-authored work of 1962, The Calculus of Consent , he
argued that a political system consisting of single chamber making decisions by
50 percent plus one basis could not amount to a process of political exchange.
If a reliable majority was secured that would amount to a political monopoly, and consequently
constraints should be imposed on such majorities. This was not undemocratic since
such constraints would be approved consensually before the political contest
began. Buchanan’s analogy was with a game of cards; before the cards are dealt all
players agree to the rules that will make the game work. These rules are the
constitution, and constitution is essential to healthy democratic politics. Strongly
under the sway of US constitutional tradition, Buchanan was seeking to
retell the wisdom of his country’s founding fathers to their 20th c
descendents.
Buchanan’s confidence
in the US political system faltered in the tumult of 1960s, that included bombing
of the office of his head of department at UCLA. He saw the spread of ‘constitutional
chaos’ underwritten by an unholy alliance of Democrats and Republicans to repeal
the ‘unwritten’ prohibition of budget deficits. The fall of the Berlin Wall 1991
brought him little sense of triumph; socialism is dead, he said, but ‘Leviathan
lives on’. And while the economists who had that supplied the matter for his ‘economic
theory of politics’ were no longer beholden to myth of the benevolent state, they were no
longer beholden to anything: they were ’ideological eunuchs’, engrossed in make-believe
world of pure theory, that he compared to science fantasy. Of the economics of
the last generation, he said ‘I am
reminded’ of J. K. Tolkien, ‘who through sheer power of imagination created a
whole new world of beings, the hobbit world, in his trilogy, The Lord of the
Rings. The analogy is revealing when we recall that Tolkien was writing fairy
tales for children.’
Buchanan had the
greatness that allowed him to fruitfully cultivate his contradictions; the wish
debunk political romance with an attraction to
that of his own; a readiness to deploy scientific method while maintaining a philosophic
texture of mind; to be both alienated from his country and and to love it; to
deny all the gods and to give thanks to them.
No comments:
Post a Comment